[Date Prev][Date Next][Thread Prev][Thread Next][Date Index][Thread Index]
RE: Wiley-Blackwell 2009 Subscription and Licensing Options
- To: <liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu>
- Subject: RE: Wiley-Blackwell 2009 Subscription and Licensing Options
- From: "Nawin" <nawin.gupta@comcast.net>
- Date: Tue, 7 Oct 2008 19:24:27 EDT
- Reply-to: liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
- Sender: owner-liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
Speaking as a journal publisher, I echo the views already expressed that journal publishers do not set prices based on costs, however, they do track revenues and costs to assess value and profitability. It is customary for most journal publishers to track P&L of journals portfolio at the journal level, allocating indirect costs to individual journals based on established measures and drivers. Art of managing a portfolio is to maximize the reach, readership, and revenues (and, yes, profitability) of the portfolio and, to the extent possible, each individual journal. For example, a start-up journal may be priced low or, in another instance, a journal may lose money but provides value to portfolio as a whole. Pricing of the journal is not in cost-plus, it is in the value it provides in the competitive marketplace and is further guided by publisher's business model/strategy for the journal. For example, limited market at higher price or larger market at lower price, and what other revenue opportunities (such as advertising) a larger circulation may offer. Nawin Gupta nawin.gupta@comcast.net www.nawingupta.com -----Original Message----- From: owner-liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu [mailto:owner-liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu] On Behalf Of Joseph J. Esposito Sent: Monday, October 06, 2008 5:12 PM To: liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu Subject: Re: Wiley-Blackwell 2009 Subscription and Licensing Options Thomas Krichel's wit is worthy of Swift, but the underlying economic principle of his entertaining satire is simply wrong. Publishers do not set prices based on costs, even in not-for-profits, and they can't, any more than we can slow down the speed of light so that the less advantaged can catch up. Publishers cannot set prices from costs because they do not know what those costs are. They establish prices, to a greater or lesser degree of sophistication, through an assessment of the markeplace. This is not because publishers are ignorant of the structure of their own operations (though some have faulty or incomplete analyses of those costs), but because the costs are unknowable. Publishers, including not-for-profit publishers, base their decisions on market forecasts, and they do so even when they think they are simply adding some margin to costs. As William Goldman famously said, Nobody knows anything. If this sounds inordinately cranky or mysterious, consider what it would mean to "get at" the costs. Imagine the publisher of ten journals, whose fixed costs (staff, rent, etc.) run at $5 million a year. (I am ignoring variable costs--paper, printing, bandwidth, etc.-- for this discussion.) How to allocate those fixed costs to each journal? A discussion thus ensues about whether the overhead is to be allocated equally or by some other measure (e.g., Journal A gets a higher allocation than Journal B because the art department puts more work into it). In the end you come up with a figure for costs that is derived from an economic model for assessing overhead. The "cost" is an economic abstraction. This is a small part of the reason that nobody knows anything. The larger part is that the abstraction known as "cost" has to be applied to unit sales: it is necessary to forecast (using a mathematical model) how many customers will be found, when they will sign up, and how rapidly they will pay their bills. Let's suppose that Journal B of the example above had allocated costs of $300,000. Will this journal reach 500 paying customers? One thousand? Two thousand? If we knew what the costs were, we wouldn't have to ask this question, but the cost is not a real item but an element of a dynamic economic model. With a forecast (How reliable is that crystal ball?) of 500 customers, Journal B has an imputed cost of $600/unit. With a forecast of 1,000 customers, the "cost" is cut in half. To which figure does a publisher add on margin? At every moment the publisher is making decisions not from the inside out (costs to the marketplace) but outside in (from a forecast about the marketplace in to an assessment of the utilization of organizational resources). This yields the basic paradox of a scalable business such as publishing: the best way to reduce costs is to sell more copies. There are times when publishers can and do ignore this situation, and that is when the market forecast is a constant. Let's suppose that Journal C has an imputed overhead of $200,000, has been published for years, and has for at least 5 year or thereabouts had the same number of subscribers--say, 1,000. With such a stable market condition, the publisher assumes costs of about $200 per unit and then adds on some margin to that. Without that stable market condition, however, this method does not work. The limitations of this shorthand should be clear: it is impossible to introduce a new product using it, as new products require market forecasts, which vary; and products in dynamic markets (a growing or diminishing number of customers) require that publishers revisit their economic models regularly. If you happen to believe, as I do, that the number of current publications and content types is but a tiny fraction of what we will be seeing in the years ahead, the "cost-plus" shorthand is of negligible utility. This thread began with Fred Friend asking, Why does the stuff cost so darn much? It's a reasonable question. But we can't get to an answer by impugning people's motives or engaging in financially unsophisticated arguments. The crisis of scholarly communications is that a small number of people want a real lot of stuff. It is thus a small and expensive market to serve. Joe Esposito
- Prev by Date: Re: Wiley-Blackwell 2009 Subscription and Licensing Options
- Next by Date: Revoked Open Access?
- Previous by thread: Re: Wiley-Blackwell 2009 Subscription and Licensing Options
- Next by thread: Re: Wiley-Blackwell 2009 Subscription and Licensing Options
- Index(es):