[Date Prev][Date Next][Thread Prev][Thread Next][Date Index][Thread Index]
RE: Price discrimination for academic subscriptions (discussion)
- To: liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
- Subject: RE: Price discrimination for academic subscriptions (discussion)
- From: Ann Okerson <ann.okerson@yale.edu>
- Date: Sun, 7 Sep 2003 15:24:26 -0400 (EDT)
- Reply-to: liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
- Sender: owner-liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
Phil: Your questions and comments are good ones; it's long seemed to me that in e-world, publishers are trying to find good and fair ways of charging by usage level, whether it be by utilizing FTE counts, or FTEs enrolled in a given program, or Carnegie Class, or actual usage levels. And my guess is that increasingly prices will correspond somehow to usage levels. (Sometimes the customer can set usage levels, for example, where publishers offer a Simultaneous User model, libraries can pick that number, which is tied to pricing, but that's not usual for full text journals.) You ask what we can expect as longer-term effects if we do move explicitly to some form of usage-based pricing. At the moment, it's hard to tell, as our usage data are still very primitive, so publishers and librarians are being understandably cautious about "going there." As one who believes that dialog between publishers and librarians can and is being productive and useful, I'll try not to sound too cynical when I say that most publishers have an annual "bottom line" target that they need or want to meet. And so, usage-based pricing is likely to be arranged so that the revenues add up to that bottom line. So, you're at research-intensive, information-voracious Cornell -- you may be asked to pay more for ejournals than you would have paid for your print sub; whereas Clem Smedley, at Little College, will be asked to pay a miniscule sum, far less than he would have paid in print (print prices couldn't easily be nuanced). There are one or two early signs that usage based pricing could be very hard on research intensive universities, even as (perhaps) it will be neutral or beneficial for small schools or developing countries (see the many for-free offerings available for the latter at: <http://www.library.yale.edu/~llicense/develop.shtml>. For example, just last week, one particularly important scientific publisher wrote that he/it is facing advertising revenue loss. This publisher notified its largest customers that price for our group will be related to usage *and* in those cases the prices are increasing by a whopping amount (doubling or more in our case). Someone has cynically suggested that the solution for us is to hide those ejournals and make sure that as few users as possible find them. Yet if the biggest users, i.e., research-intensive schools, cannot afford to purchase some core titles, those titles do face a good chance of withering and becoming far less core. When that happens, no one wins. Ann Okerson/Yale Library ann.okerson@yale.edu On Wed, 3 Sep 2003, Phil Davis wrote: > Heather Morrison provided an excellent response and discussion to my > original post regarding price discrimination. Without diverting into > arguing over specific details, I would like to resubmit for discussion > that any institutional classification (FTE, Carnegie Class, number of > biologists, etc), are merely estimates of real (or potential) use. Are > the consequences for paying for what you use any different than paying for > what you *may be likely to use*. In other words, what would be the > economic effects of moving to an economic pricing model whereby an > institutions's price is at least partly based on that institution's usage > pattern? > > --Phil Davis
- Prev by Date: Re: copyright protection paper
- Next by Date: On the Need to Take Both Roads to Open Access
- Previous by thread: RE: Price discrimination for academic subscriptions (discussion)
- Next by thread: RE: Price discrimination for academic subscriptions (discussion)
- Index(es):