[Date Prev][Date Next][Thread Prev][Thread Next][Date Index][Thread Index]
RE: Price discrimination for academic subscriptions (discussion)
- To: <liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu>
- Subject: RE: Price discrimination for academic subscriptions (discussion)
- From: "David Goodman" <David.Goodman@liu.edu>
- Date: Mon, 8 Sep 2003 18:02:04 EDT
- Reply-to: liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
- Sender: owner-liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
It should not be overlooked that the practice of charging flat rates is also discriminatory pricing: it discriminates strongly in favor of the largest schools. (This was less true in the print era when the largest schools would hold multiple print subscriptions to important journals, thus effectively producing a curve.) Use-based pricing also needs a curve of some sort: most schools would be much more willing to pay $35/article for Biochim Biophys Acta, where they might need 50 articles a year, than they would for Cell, where they might need 500, to mention two journals from the same publisher. Even for the same journal, a school without a ecology department might need 10 articles a year from Oecologia (price about $4000/yr--different publisher, btw), and be willing to pay $35 each; a school with a large department might need 1000, and be less willing. (All numbers are obviously merely illustrative, but no likely variation of them will lead to a different conclusion.) There are two hidden factors that greatly affect the impact of any per-use scheme. First, once an institution has purchased an article, is there an additional charge for other users of the article from the same institution? If there is, it greatly increases the cost for the larger institutions, if not, it favors them. Second, is there an additional charge if the same individual user accesses an article a second time? If so, it provides a strong incentive for users to store everything they have read on a local hard disk, rather than by saving the links, which may not be the most efficient way of working. If not, it requires tracking the individual users, which most of us would find totally unacceptable. (An alternative which might possibly be workable is a complicated retrieval code system). I note as a further complication that pricing differently depending upon whether an article, is read, printed, or downloaded is now technicaly feasible. One can obviously have various combination schemes, typically involving a ceiling price, often the traditional subscription price. All of these yield the same problems as now, that of deterining the appropriate price curve. In any case, any model of per-use pricing eliminates the possibility for a research institution to own and archive the complete contents of a journal. I do not think there can be any equitable business model for the typical STM journal in its present form. For the user, only open access of some sort is equitable. Models such as PLOS or BMC meet this criterion, but then raise problems for authors of different abilities to pay, though the questions of equity may prove less intractable at the producer end. I conclude the only truly equitable model to be a open archives proposal similar to the arXiv model, or the original Harnad or Varmus proposals. Studying or debating which scheme of charging extortionate prices is the least unfair is not a productive approach. Dr. David Goodman Associate Professor Palmer School of Library and Information Science Long Island University dgoodman@liu.edu
- Prev by Date: Congress preparing to extend databases' copyright protections?
- Next by Date: Re: Lawmakers to Weigh Database Protection Bill
- Previous by thread: RE: Price discrimination for academic subscriptions (discussion)
- Next by thread: RE: Price discrimination for academic subscriptions (discussion)
- Index(es):