[Date Prev][Date Next][Thread Prev][Thread Next][Date Index][Thread Index]
Economic Thoughts on the Google Book Settlement
- To: liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
- Subject: Economic Thoughts on the Google Book Settlement
- From: Ahmed Hindawi <ahmed.hindawi@hindawi.com>
- Date: Sat, 15 Aug 2009 15:20:45 EDT
- Reply-to: liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
- Sender: owner-liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
Something that is clear to me is that Google must be planning to use the current Book archive it has in order to tap into the book sales market in general (meaning that it will be selling the newly published books as well). They are coming from a different angle than Amazon.com, but they will most certainly have their eye on a market that is currently worth tens of billions of dollars. Especially that it is not clear that online advertising money will continue to increase and even if it does, the horizon of this market might be in sight. Google can double its current revenue if it became the world "Book Distributor" to individuals and organizations. First, I have two questions that I hope someone can answer them for me (or tell me that there is no such answer at the moment). Then, I would like to share some thoughts about the economic problems and consequences of a particular scenario that might actually take place. First the two questions: (1) Will Google have the right to creating sub-collections and licensing them to different organizations (households?, individuals?)? Does the settlement give this right of slicing the collection it sub-collections? Can Google create the "Google Mathematics Book Collection" or the "Google Social Science Collection" or the "Google Science Fiction Collection" and license them to libraries, or is Google bound by selling only licenses to its whole collection. (2) Who will determine how the revenue of licenses will be divided between the rights holders (after Google takes its cut according to the settlement)? This question is always faced by aggregators selling cross-publisher content to libraries (e.g., ALPSP Learned Journal Collection or the O'Reilly's Safari book collection). Most of time, the solution relies on using the "current" market price of the items within the collection (subscription rates for journals or cover price of books) and/or usage levels by the subscribing library. Google will have hard time doing either of these, as I will explain below. The first problem with using the "current" market price is that with many books being out of print and for quite some time, there is no "current" market price. However, even if Google can figure something out to use some sort of cover price of books to distribute the money between rights holders, this cover price can only be used as long as publishers will not "adjust" them (for newly published books) to give themselves an unfair portion of the revenue. If I price my journal at $100,000 in a cross-publisher journal collection to get a larger share, I will penalize my direct subscription revenue which usually is the major revenue stream. However, in a world where I am only relying on the collection revenue stream, I will inflate my prices as much as I can, to get the maximum possible revenue share from the collection. Clearly this can be a problem if the Google revenue generated from site licenses become big enough (say $20b) for publishers to "concentrate on it" and forget the rest of the market. So, may be Google (or the Publishers Association or the Authors Guild) should forget about the cover price and split the money based on usage without taking the cover price into account. But this can be problematic. A publisher of a Mathematics book with potential audience of 500 people will not be happy to share the revenue with a trade book publisher based on usage only. This is the reason why Mathematics books are more expensive in the market in first place. The cost of producing them, divided by the number of "page views" they generate is much higher than regular trade book. Aggregate collections (of any materials) can work with their revenue divided between their content producers (publishers or rights holders) based on usage only if the usage is correlated with the cost of producing them. As an example, consider netflix: movie studios are happy letting them stream movies to their subscribers and they get a fee per view because although there is a movie that costed $300m to produce and another the costed $30m to produce and a third that costed $3m to produce, the usage of the three movies (the number of people interested in seeing the movie at the same price) tend to be 100:10:1 or close to that ratio. This is why most movie DVDs are comparable in prices regardless of the huge difference between the movie production budgets. If you produce a $300m movie, you get your money back largely because many people will want to watch it and not because you charge $200 for its DVD. My point is, if you aggregate these types of contents together in a single product and license it, content producers (assuming that they are happy with the total revenue generated by the collection to start with) will be willing to agree on a flat per usage formula. For other types of content, the whole system breaks down. Trying to create a book collection with scholarly books that are generally expensive to produce and fiction books that are generally inexpensive to produce while having a negative correlation between the potential usage of the two groups will most certainly be objectionable to the scholarly book publishers. If Google can actually create sub-collections or similar material, it may be able to tackle this problem to some degree at least, hence my first question. One interesting thing to notice here is that if we convert to large collection licenses like these (in which case the cover price cannot be used as a bases to distribute the revenue between publishers), and if we rely on usage to distribute the revenue, we will be in a total "page view economy." Just like the current media companies which are relying on advertising which is base on the number of page views they can generate for their content. The only difference (and it is a very important difference) is that instead of the publisher getting $1 for every 1000 page views, they will get, say, $12 for every 1000 page views (this would be like reading 4 books of 250 page each for $3 each book). This would be a world where publishers are competing to produce materials that attract readership, because they know that the more people read their book (which is free at the point of consumption), the larger percentage they will get from that license fee at the end of the year. Is this a bad thing, not necessary. It can actually be a very good thing. The fundamental problem is, you need to slice the collection enough to make everyone happy (even within Mathematics, a publisher of a K* Algebra for graduate students will not want to compete based on page views with an a Junior level Numerical Analysis book publisher). When items are sold separately, market prices solve this problem: you can price your K* Algebra at a higher price and the few people who want to read it, will be willing to pay this higher price for it. Prices really play a very important role in the economy and when/if we create a new world based on large cross-publisher collection licenses, we need to find a way of recreating the market mechanisms within the aggregation in order to reward publishers who produce materials that are expensive to produce and at the same time have limited potential use. Otherwise, the system will force these publishers out of the market and there will be no venues for such content to be produce and consumed. In a hypothetical world where all of publishers revenue are coming from these large collections, publishers will care about the quality (both the editorial quality and the production quality) because they want to maximize the usage of their published materials. They will not have sales forces (another saving in addition to the print, binding, shipping, etc.), but will probably have larger marketing departments. They will want to want everyone to know about their books and to encourage everyone to read it (hey, it is free at the point of use, so they cannot lower their price to entice potential readers, they can only try to increase the quality of their published materials). Any thoughts? Ahmed Hindawi
- Prev by Date: Informa Healthcare: Journals migrating to new site
- Next by Date: Re: Scholarly communication, copyright, and fair use
- Previous by thread: Informa Healthcare: Journals migrating to new site
- Next by thread: RE: Economic Thoughts on the Google Book Settlement
- Index(es):