[Date Prev][Date Next][Thread Prev][Thread Next][Date Index][Thread Index]
RE: Wiley-Blackwell 2009 Subscription and Licensing Options
- To: <liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu>
- Subject: RE: Wiley-Blackwell 2009 Subscription and Licensing Options
- From: "Sally Morris \(Morris Associates\)" <sally@morris-assocs.demon.co.uk>
- Date: Tue, 7 Oct 2008 19:23:50 EDT
- Reply-to: liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
- Sender: owner-liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
I find Joe's perspective (as ever) very refreshing However, I'd take issue with one point: surely the best way to reduce total costs (in the print world, anyway) is to sell as few copies as possible? A publisher would make considerably more profit selling one copy at $1000 than selling 1000 copies at $1. Fortunately for all of us, the journals market is sufficiently competitive (and sensible) for this not to happen! Sally Morris Consultant, Morris Associates (Publishing Consultancy) South House, The Street Clapham, Worthing, West Sussex BN13 3UU, UK Email: sally@morris-assocs.demon.co.uk -----Original Message----- From: owner-liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu [mailto:owner-liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu] On Behalf Of Joseph J. Esposito Sent: 06 October 2008 23:12 To: liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu Subject: Re: Wiley-Blackwell 2009 Subscription and Licensing Options Thomas Krichel's wit is worthy of Swift, but the underlying economic principle of his entertaining satire is simply wrong. Publishers do not set prices based on costs, even in not-for-profits, and they can't, any more than we can slow down the speed of light so that the less advantaged can catch up. Publishers cannot set prices from costs because they do not know what those costs are. They establish prices, to a greater or lesser degree of sophistication, through an assessment of the markeplace. This is not because publishers are ignorant of the structure of their own operations (though some have faulty or incomplete analyses of those costs), but because the costs are unknowable. Publishers, including not-for-profit publishers, base their decisions on market forecasts, and they do so even when they think they are simply adding some margin to costs. As William Goldman famously said, Nobody knows anything. If this sounds inordinately cranky or mysterious, consider what it would mean to "get at" the costs. Imagine the publisher of ten journals, whose fixed costs (staff, rent, etc.) run at $5 million a year. (I am ignoring variable costs--paper, printing, bandwidth, etc.-- for this discussion.) How to allocate those fixed costs to each journal? A discussion thus ensues about whether the overhead is to be allocated equally or by some other measure (e.g., Journal A gets a higher allocation than Journal B because the art department puts more work into it). In the end you come up with a figure for costs that is derived from an economic model for assessing overhead. The "cost" is an economic abstraction. This is a small part of the reason that nobody knows anything. The larger part is that the abstraction known as "cost" has to be applied to unit sales: it is necessary to forecast (using a mathematical model) how many customers will be found, when they will sign up, and how rapidly they will pay their bills. Let's suppose that Journal B of the example above had allocated costs of $300,000. Will this journal reach 500 paying customers? One thousand? Two thousand? If we knew what the costs were, we wouldn't have to ask this question, but the cost is not a real item but an element of a dynamic economic model. With a forecast (How reliable is that crystal ball?) of 500 customers, Journal B has an imputed cost of $600/unit. With a forecast of 1,000 customers, the "cost" is cut in half. To which figure does a publisher add on margin? At every moment the publisher is making decisions not from the inside out (costs to the marketplace) but outside in (from a forecast about the marketplace in to an assessment of the utilization of organizational resources). This yields the basic paradox of a scalable business such as publishing: the best way to reduce costs is to sell more copies. There are times when publishers can and do ignore this situation, and that is when the market forecast is a constant. Let's suppose that Journal C has an imputed overhead of $200,000, has been published for years, and has for at least 5 year or thereabouts had the same number of subscribers--say, 1,000. With such a stable market condition, the publisher assumes costs of about $200 per unit and then adds on some margin to that. Without that stable market condition, however, this method does not work. The limitations of this shorthand should be clear: it is impossible to introduce a new product using it, as new products require market forecasts, which vary; and products in dynamic markets (a growing or diminishing number of customers) require that publishers revisit their economic models regularly. If you happen to believe, as I do, that the number of current publications and content types is but a tiny fraction of what we will be seeing in the years ahead, the "cost-plus" shorthand is of negligible utility. This thread began with Fred Friend asking, Why does the stuff cost so darn much? It's a reasonable question. But we can't get to an answer by impugning people's motives or engaging in financially unsophisticated arguments. The crisis of scholarly communications is that a small number of people want a real lot of stuff. It is thus a small and expensive market to serve. Joe Esposito ----- Original Message ----- From: "Thomas Krichel" <krichel@openlib.org> To: <liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu> Sent: Friday, October 03, 2008 3:28 PM Subject: Re: Wiley-Blackwell 2009 Subscription and Licensing Options > Joseph Esposito writes > >> I suppose there are some publishers who justify prices based on >> the costs incurred, but I have never met any of them. >> Publishers typically justify prices (if they feel the need to >> justify them) based on the value of the products. > > I suppose there are some publishers who justify prices based on > the value provided, but I have never met any of them. I doubt > I'll meet any of them soon. How would a publisher be able to set > a dollar amount for that value in any objective way? > > Cheers, > > Thomas Krichel http://openlib.org/home/krichel > RePEc:per:1965-06-05:thomas_krichel > skype: thomaskrichel
- Prev by Date: Re: Wiley-Blackwell 2009 Subscription and Licensing Options
- Next by Date: Re: Wiley-Blackwell 2009 Subscription and Licensing Options
- Previous by thread: Re: Wiley-Blackwell 2009 Subscription and Licensing Options
- Next by thread: Re: Wiley-Blackwell 2009 Subscription and Licensing Options
- Index(es):