[Date Prev][Date Next][Thread Prev][Thread Next][Date Index][Thread Index]
Re: Post Brussels : the economics of editors
- To: liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
- Subject: Re: Post Brussels : the economics of editors
- From: Phil Davis <pmd8@cornell.edu>
- Date: Mon, 5 Mar 2007 18:37:12 EST
- Reply-to: liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
- Sender: owner-liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
Imperfect information allows for market inefficiencies, but in this case, Joe is forgetting that editors derive as much (or more) from their relationships with publishers than the often mediocre honoraria they receive in return. Editors are mostly paid in an abstract commodity called "prestige", which can be translated into worldly goods within the academy (advancement, grants and awards, people) and let us not forget the powerful position of being a gatekeeper of what is published. We cannot simply consider editors to be employees of a publishing house. Such a narrow view only focuses on monetary transaction between the two actors and ignores the more valuable transfer of prestige.
--Phil Davis
At 09:22 PM 3/4/2007, you wrote:
So here we have in Colin Steele's post a perfect illustration of why the theory of "non-rival goods," beloved by economists, does not apply to information. Steele tells the world that publishers pay authors and reviewers nothing or almost nothing, and publishers say barely a word in their defense. Why? Because to acknowledge (the truth) that many editors receive small sums and a lucky few princely payments would encourage more editors to demand more, and the more they get, to the extent that this fact is publicized, the more they will demand. Thus publishers conceal the information because it is better to be misunderstood than to be poor. The value of the information as to what is actually going on disappears when the information is widely available. Sometimes information gains in value when it is widely shared (e.g., advertising), sometimes the value is in withholding it from others. Think about buying or selling a stock: Should you share what you know? Open Access advocates may like to add this item to their simulations. Anthony Watkinson is of course correct on the point about editorial remuneration, though why he should become a turncoat to the brotherhood of self-interested publishers, I cannot imagine. You shall not dine on the flesh of authors this season, Anthony! Joe Esposito On 3/2/07, Colin Steele <Colin.Steele@anu.edu.au> wrote:My hopefully still good friend Anthony Watkinson hasn't commented on most of the original points below, but I thought the debate on academic contributions to scholarship and payments had been touched upon in the emails on Liblicense in January, for example, see the debate stimulated by Peter Banks and Dr Andrew Adams and the now somewhat related parallel discussion currently being promulgated on the American Scientist list by Jan Velterop and others, "contempt for the scientist as author and communicator". I was really commenting on the lack of Australian evidence of substantial remuneration to academics for their contributions to research publications, ranging from peer review through editorial board representation and even through to Editor-in-Chief of journals. I was not referring to paid employees of the publishing firms themselves. These reflections were made on the basis of questions asked to a number of leading researchers over the years, including those at ANU, and also from a nationwide CAVAL tour last year when we were discussing the Australian RQF Framework with a range of academics, including PVCs and DVCs Research. Nowhere did it seem that Australian academics were being significantly remunerated, if at all, for the amount of work they were putting in to publishing across the Disciplines, including Social Sciences and Humanities. If there is evidence to the contrary, we would be happy to have it cited, eg regarding office space, administrative support, consultancy fees, etc that is paid for by the publisher, etc. Sandy Thatcher has just indicated to the list that Penn State don't. Two anecdotal comments. Meeting with a senior executive of one of the top six multinationals in Canberra a couple of years ago (not Elsevier) he saw one of his Editors across the room and mentioned his connection with the publishing firm. I asked the executive how much the editor received and he said "Nothing, if we did we would have to raise subscription prices". Secondly, a major ANU academic in the Humanities was asked to review a 600 page book manuscript for a major American University Press. I asked him how much time this took and he said two weeks of my annual leave. Next question was, what remuneration did you get and he said, the fee then (in 2005) was 250 US dollars or $400 worth of press books. He said "of course I took the press books". I then said "for two weeks work?". Similar figures had been quoted a major UK academic press but again, its better to have the remuneration available if possible. I don't think academics generally mind? In relation to my initial EPS quote, I note that at least I am in good/bad company (depending on one's view point) given the Association of Research Libraries make similar comments in their 'Issue Brief on Wiley's acquisition of Blackwell', February 26, 2007. (http://www.arl.org/bm~doc/issue_brief_wiley_blackwell.pdf) Excerpt: "This document briefly outlines the growing dysfunction in the journal market resulting from the exercise of market power by an ever-shrinking group of large commercial publishers. This planned consolidation within an already concentrated market immediately raised concerns within the library community. Libraries have observed significant dysfunctions in the scholarly journal market place for some time. Costs for resources continue the trend of past decades in rising well in excess of background inflation. Numerous studies have documented that journals from the largest commercial publishers cost many times more than comparable journals from not-for-profit publishers. In addition, prices rise more rapidly following large acquisitions. A spiral of rising prices and ongoing market concentration squeezes out support for small society journals. It is very difficult for other publishers to start new scholarly journals in the current marketplace. The advent of electronic journal formats and large publisher bundles have increased the ability of merging companies to exercise market power to raise prices and direct compensatory cancellations onto other publishers' journals. History shows that mergers of large journal publishers lead to price increases." ********** Colin
- Prev by Date: Re: Query Re Library Responsibility for Library Patrons' Use
- Next by Date: RE: Query Re Library Responsibility for Library Patrons' Use
- Previous by thread: Collection development position at Oberlin
- Next by thread: RE: Post Brussels : the economics of editors
- Index(es):