Previous by Date |
Index by Date
Threaded Index |
Next by Date |
---|---|---|
Previous by Thread | Next by Thread |
Re: Costs of Electronic Resources
In response to Dianne Nicholson and the moderator: >... Can we discuss the modes of >charging for electronic resources and hear from producers about how they >create their pricing mechanisms? Thanks to Dianne for starting this >thread.] > My company provides electronic publications in the legal market in Sydney Australia. Our products are all intranet based. That is, we supply our customers with a copy of our HTML database which they keep locally on their network server. We then use email to send attachments to our program at the clients site to update their copy of the database weekly or even daily, if necessary. We provide a high frequency update service for users on corporate intranets. As a new company with no baggage, I considered long and hard various options for licensing. I had a predisposition against the concurrent user model because it requires us to run software on the client site to enforce. My experience in the market indicated that without this, some customers would underestimate the number of concurrent users if left to their own devices. We would not survive if that happened on any scale. In addition, it is almost impossible to budget for prices based on concurrent users until you have a long history of the pattern of use in various organisations. As a new entrant with no realistic way to assess likely concurrent use in large firms, I could not set a budget. I needed a simpler and more objective standard than concurrent user pricing. This is how I went about choosing a pricing model: 1. I looked at the market I could access and worked out how much I needed from the products as a whole to service our expectations and obligations; 2. I looked at the prices being charged by competitors and decided where I could fit into the market in a competitive sense. 3. An underlying proposition is that viewed broadly, large organisations should pay more than small organisations. Even though our cost of delivery is much the same, a difference is needed because in our case, with a fairly small market, an average price would be too high for small firms to justify. In addition, the service is inherently more valuable to a larger firm than a smaller firm. 4. I worked out approximate price levels I could expect various size firms to pay for site licenses and then set about devising a model to produce the required fees. In the end I adopted this: Base fee or a single user (eg $2,000). PLUS, for network use, an incremental fee (eg $40) for each machine which provides permanent access to the service. Law firms etc may take out a site licence on the basis of the number of licensed lawyers and provide unlimited access to all persons, including para legals etc at no extra charge. In the case of libraries who provide terminals for general access. I have so far applied the same incremental fee even though I sometimes think this may be too generous. Overall I see it as swings and roundabouts. We allow dial up access (home to work) from persons who are otherwise within the licensed group at no additional charge. The effect of our pricing is that the average cost per user at each site is much lower for large organisations. This reflects the fact that there is a minimum cost of providing the service and support. To supply smaller organisations we need to offer the service over the internet so it is more affordable for casual or infrequent use. I apologise if this is a bit long but it is an interesting and difficult subject. Peter Meyer Managing Director Desktop Law Pty Ltd ______________________________________________________________________________ DESKTOP LAW - Legal publication services Desktop Law Pty Limited Ph: +61 2 9922 3096 PO Box 244, Lindfield, NSW 2070 Fax: +61 2 9929 8396 Peter W Meyer pmeyer@desklaw.com.au
http://www.library.yale.edu/liblicense © 1996, 1997 Yale University Library |
Please read our Disclaimer E-mail us with feedback |