[Date Prev][Date Next][Thread Prev][Thread Next][Date Index][Thread Index]
Re: Article in "Inside HigherEd"
- To: liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
- Subject: Re: Article in "Inside HigherEd"
- From: richards1000@comcast.net
- Date: Thu, 26 Mar 2009 17:49:46 EDT
- Reply-to: liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
- Sender: owner-liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
Thanks to everyone for a very interesting exchange. This is my understanding of the exchange so far. Respecting the issue of information overload, some economists employ the idea of "consumer search costs." See, e.g., Landes & Posner, Trademark Law: An Economic Perspective, 30 Journal of Law & Economics 265 (1987). An excess of potentially relevant, accessible information imposes substantial information-processing costs on the user of information ("consumer search costs"). Joe Esposito and Sally Morris identify two well-tested tools for lowering consumer search costs: (1) brands and (2) technology that retrieves, filters, organizes, and enables the management of information ("information-management tools"). I agree with Sally Morris that at what point in the information life cycle, and on whom, the toll to produce quality information (i.e., payment for information production costs) is assessed are separate issues from, and are often causally unrelated to, consumer search costs. The principal causes of high consumer search costs appear to be (a) a high quantity of potentially relevant, accessible information, coupled with (b) comparatively low effectiveness of brands and consumers' information-management tools. Consumer search costs decline to the extent that the quantity of potentially relevant, accessible information declines, or the effectiveness of brands and/or consumers' information-management tools increases. As Joe Esposito, Sally Morris, and others rightly point out, nothing (neither tolls, nor anything else) appears to be reducing the quantity of potentially relevant, accessible scholarly information. Accordingly, brands and consumers' information-management tools would seem to warrant substantial attention from those of us who are concerned with lowering scholars' consumer search costs. (Lowering such costs appears to be the meaning of Ranganathan's "law": "Save the time of the reader.") Dean Coates's article suggests that information-management tools for some, and perhaps most scholars, might still need substantial improvement. I agree with Jan Velterop that knowledge-level and other "intelligent" features could greatly improve the effectiveness of scholars' information-management tools. I agree with those who have argued on this list that what is needed is the wide availability of effective, intelligent, end-user information-management applications that are built in to scholars' reading devices (handhelds, PCs, ebook readers, etc.), and that operate to a very great extent automatically and invisibly. ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ Robert C. Richards, Jr., J.D.*, M.S.L.I.S., M.A. Law Librarian & Legal Information Consultant Philadelphia, PA richards1000@comcast.net ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
- Prev by Date: RE: Article in "Inside HigherEd"
- Next by Date: RE: Article in "Inside HigherEd"
- Previous by thread: RE: Article in "Inside HigherEd"
- Next by thread: RE: Article in "Inside HigherEd"
- Index(es):