[Date Prev][Date Next][Thread Prev][Thread Next][Date Index][Thread Index]
RE: the Yale argument on open-choice
- To: <liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu>
- Subject: RE: the Yale argument on open-choice
- From: "Sally Morris \(Morris Associates\)" <sally@morris-assocs.demon.co.uk>
- Date: Thu, 22 Mar 2007 18:15:39 EDT
- Reply-to: liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
- Sender: owner-liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
I'd like to clarify a few points: If you look at the average price increases for journals, they correspond more or less to three drivers: Increase in the number of papers processed Fall in the number of subscribers Underlying cost inflation I see no evidence that publishers (of any type), these days, are driving prices up as hard as they can; this may have been the case in the heady days of the late 70s/early 80s when library funds seemed to be bottomless (!), but publishers have long since woken up to the negative consequences of alienating their customers through unreasonable price increases. Of course, the introduction of increasingly flexible and innovative licensing models has meant that, in recent years, the price paid per journal has actually begun to fall (see both ARL and LISU figures) Secondly, ownership or otherwise of copyright has nothing to do with anything - this is a widespread and unhelpful misunderstanding. It all depends on the precise wording of the agreement between author and publisher. A growing number of publishers offer 'licence to publish' agreements which leave copyright with the author (or their employer, depending on their situation). These, however, can - if well worded - allocate to author and to publisher exactly the same rights; the best of them always endeavour to secure for the publisher the rights it needs, while securing for the author all the rights she needs (short of those which would actually damage the publisher). There are various model agreements about - see, for example, those on the ALPSP website Sally Morris Consultant, Morris Associates (Publishing Consultancy) South House, The Street Clapham, Worthing, West Sussex BN13 3UU, UK Email: sally@morris-assocs.demon.co.uk *** [mailto:owner-liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu] On Behalf Of Matthew Cockerill Sent: 21 March 2007 21:25 To: liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu Subject: Re: the Yale argument on open-choice Is it not clear, though, hat price inflation is an expected consequence of the subscription model? If the research community hands over ownership/exclusive rights to publishers, it is economically predictable that publishers (whether commercial or not-for-profit) will charge as much as they can in order to maximize their revenues. Given that the academic community *really* needs access to that research, there is virtually no upper bound on what publishers with enough market power can get away with charging for subscriptions . The natural solution to this is surely for the research community *not* to give away the ownership/exclusive rights to the research. Under an open access publishing model, you immediately have a much more effective market. The customer (the research community) can choose the publication service that offers the best value, ensuring that prices are kept down. This kind of 'substitutability' generally doesn't exist with the subscription model - hence the problem of journal inflation. Matt Cockerill BioMed Central
- Prev by Date: Re: Clarification on SERU proposal
- Next by Date: Re: Clarification on SERU proposal
- Previous by thread: Re: the Yale argument on open-choice
- Next by thread: RE: the Yale argument on open-choice
- Index(es):