[Date Prev][Date Next][Thread Prev][Thread Next][Date Index][Thread Index]
RE: Decision making by Libraries on serials and monographs and useage (re puzzled by self-archiving thread)
- To: <liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu>
- Subject: RE: Decision making by Libraries on serials and monographs and useage (re puzzled by self-archiving thread)
- From: "Sally Morris" <sally@morris-assocs.demon.co.uk>
- Date: Wed, 24 Jan 2007 16:36:23 EST
- Reply-to: liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
- Sender: owner-liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
I am no economist so my questions are common-sense ones (I think) Increasing access I can understand in principle - but how does one increase 'efficiency'(as an input)? Your most prominent definitions of 'efficiency' are related to 'relevance' and I really don't see how that could be increased. Wouldn't the arguments be more convincing if one looked at the increase in just one variable, anyway? As to the one-to-one relationship between a given percentage of increased access (or anything else) and increased benefit - could you clarify that? I'm not assuming that most users have access already - just that those who do are likely to be those most able to benefit, and that ability to benefit will decline as access increases. The same would go for any impact on the efficiency of the users' own research. To a simple non-economist like me, it all seems to rest on huge and rather implausible assumptions... Sally Morris Email: sally@morris-assocs.demon.co.uk -----Original Message----- [mailto:owner-liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu] On Behalf Of John Houghton Sent: 24 January 2007 13:01 To: liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu Subject: Re: Decision making by Libraries on serials and monographs and useage (re puzzled by self-archiving thread) Dear Sally, et al. 1) As outlined in our report (pp42-46) we introduce access and efficiency as negative variables, to reflect the fact that in the real world there is less than 100% access and efficiency. The basic result is that, if accessibility and efficiency are constant over the estimation period but then show a one-off increase (e.g. because of a move to open access) then, to a close approximation, the returns to R&D will increase by the same percentage increase as that in the accessibility and efficiency parameters. There are two reasons for our using the average rate of return to R&D, rather than the marginal rate (as I think you suggest). First, conceptually, the return relates to the expenditure, and we have not altered the level of expenditure in the model (its a given). So, one could argue that we should use the average rather than marginal rate of return. Second, more practically, no one really knows the marginal rate of return to R&D. You assume that most potential users already have access. I am less confident that they do. For example: * Some smaller universities in Australia have quite limited access. If you look at recent CAUL statistics and take Victorian universities as an example, you can see that Monash (one of our larger research universities) reports 75,725 current serial titles in 2004, whereas the University of Ballarat reports 20,762. Obviously not all serials are journals, and not all the things needed at a large university will be needed at a smaller one, but such numbers are indicative of quite different levels of access - even amongst researchers. * Having an interest in the issue I often ask people in industry if and how they access journals and whether they think they would benefit from more access. It is anecdotal, but most executives of small firms in electronics, biotechnology, consulting engineering, management and economic consulting, etc. that I have spoken to say they have very limited access (mainly to print copies of titles from the one or two societies they belong to, or through association with one of the universities), and most say they need more and easier access. * Evidence of hits and downloads from institutional repositories and things like the Medline Index suggests that use is much wider than the limited audience reached by the subscription literature, both geographically and sectorally. * There is evidence that developing world participation in research is limited by their lack of timely and ready access. * etc. Many of these issues are discussed, and references given in our report. 2) Efficiency is being used in two senses... the usefulness/use of the knowledge created by R&D and the efficiency of the conduct of R&D. In the report (pp31-34 and Appendix II) we outline some of the potential impacts of enhanced access, including a range of ways in which the efficiency of research might be increased (e.g. increased speed of discovery, reduction of duplicative research, etc.) and its use might be extended (e.g. enhanced access to industry, government and society, the emergence of new industries such as weather derivatives, etc.). These are discussed in the context of developing an "impacts framework" that focuses on the issues of access, use and efficiency. Lastly, the 5% figure is in the mid-range of the 1% to 10% variation in the access and efficiency variables that we 'experimented' with in our estimations. It is hypothetical in the sense that there is no metric that led us to 5% directly. However, if one takes citation differences between subscription and OA as a possible metric, it is worth noting reported examples of OA papers getting 2-5 times the citations (e.g. Open Citation Project references). Stevan's OA Advantage work suggests that some of it will be ongoing and some not.... but twice as many citations perhaps suggests something like a 100% increase in access and use, and 5 times as many a 400% increase. So, our hypothetical 5% is probably pretty conservative when set against such metrics. On the other hand, of course, R&D produces knowledge "outputs" other than publications. Tenopir and King suggested that something up to 20% of researchers' time is spent reading and writing, so if everything that researchers do contributes to the R&D "stock of knowledge" then, simplistically, publications account for 20% of the stock of knowledge. On that basis, a 25% increase in access to publications alone would produce a 5% increase in access to the stock of knowledge (other things remaining the same). On that "logic", our 5% is perhaps at the conservative end of the kind of access impact implied by the sustainable and continuing OA Advantage. Remember, our analysis relates to any/all types of R&D outputs, not just publications and not just journal articles. Again, let me stress that this is preliminary work, the intention of which is to begin to explore possible ways to make ballpark estimates of the potential economic impacts of enhanced access. It is one possible staring point... Refs: DEST report - http://dspace.anu.edu.au/handle/1885/44485 CAUL Statistics - http://www.caul.edu.au/stats/ Regards John Houghton Centre for Strategic Economic Studies (CSES), Victoria University 21 Munro Street, Curtin, ACT 2605 AUSTRALIA E-mail: john.houghton@pobox.com Web: www.pobox.com/~houghton
- Prev by Date: Wiley and ADAA Announce Partnership
- Next by Date: Re: University of California Libraries Announce Pursuit of Value-based Journal Prices
- Previous by thread: Wiley and ADAA Announce Partnership
- Next by thread: Re: Decision making by Libraries on serials and monographs and useage (re puzzled by self-archiving thread)
- Index(es):