[Date Prev][Date Next][Thread Prev][Thread Next][Date Index][Thread Index]
Re: Institutional Journal Costs in an Open Access Environment
- To: liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
- Subject: Re: Institutional Journal Costs in an Open Access Environment
- From: Phil Davis <pmd8@cornell.edu>
- Date: Thu, 27 Apr 2006 18:08:01 EDT
- Reply-to: liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
- Sender: owner-liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
Jan, you seem to assume that critics of a producer-pays system are categorically opposed to the argument that publishing is part of the research process, and thus should be paid out of grants or the author's pocket. I am not arguing about how publishing "ought" to be funded. I am simply providing evidence that authors are generally opposed to having to pay much (if any) to publish. If citing a journal in Physics is not enough evidence, let me provide more:
Late last summer I contacted your company (Springer) to find out how many authors had opted to pay the $3,000 to make their article OA. Their response: 5
In 2004, I polled every Cornell researcher who had published in Nucleic Acids Research in the past five years whether they were willing to pay the full costs of publishing (it was $1,500 at that time, now $1,900), which would allow the library to get out of subsidizing authors through subscription costs. The alternative was for the library to pay a "membership" cost which lowered author-rates to $500. None of the authors said that they were willing to pay the full amount but were willing to pay the reduced amount. $500 is comparable to the page charges levied by good society journals in the life sciences.
Now, funding publishing on the money my institution saves through using low energy light bulbs is a fantastic idea, although we already have them. I once argued that the money saved when individuals cancelled their personal subscriptions should be sent to the library so that it can help pay our institutional subscription costs. What do you think the likelihood of this happening?
-Phil Davis
At 03:11 PM 4/26/2006, Jan Velterop wrote:
It is sort of flattering when someone takes the trouble to explain what you assume. Though sometimes it's puzzling and it can be wrong. So perhaps it helps if I interpret my assumptions myself. I know (don't need to assume) that not all grant money coming into a university stays in research. The percentages may be different in different circumstances and countries, but at Cornell it is apparently a whopping 58% that doesn't go to research. Phil argues that that makes redistribution more difficult ("we don't just have reallocation issues to deal with, we have a major shortfall"). I argue that that it makes redistribution potentially easier. A system in which 58% of a grant can be spent on other things than research (including "mowing the law" [sic] - copyright law?), is a system that should be able to deal with 59% not being spent on research per se. Especially since, after a transition period, the 1-2% of that money which now goes into the library, could be put back into research and compensate for the one percent research loss. That may not even be necessary. Just using low-energy light bulbs throughout the university or turning the heater down a notch in winter and the air condition a degree up in summer may cover the shortfall. Better for the environment anyway. But the more pertinent point is that publishing *is* part of the infrastructure for research. If paying for literature via the library can be an infrastructural provision, then paying for the literature via article charges can be. I do take the point that researchers may not happily part with money. They are people, after all. They may not happily part with money for lab glassware or chemicals, either. Or with money for mowing the lawn. That's why we have infrastructural provisions. Publishing is integral to research, and thus the cost of publishing is integral to the cost of research. Those who don't see it that way should try not publishing their research. The fact that researchers didn't like page charges in Phys Rev D ten years ago is neither here nor there. They didn't get open access for it, they were as aware of the prices of journals as cats are aware of the price of cat food (i.e. not, and they probably couldn't care less), and it wasn't an infrastructural provision (which it should have been, even then). They could rightfully see the latter as unfair. After all, researchers don't have to pay for library subscriptions, either. Jan Velterop
- Prev by Date: Re: Institutional Journal Costs in an Open Access Environment
- Next by Date: Re: Institutional Journal Costs in an Open Access Environment
- Previous by thread: Re: Institutional Journal Costs in an Open Access Environment
- Next by thread: Re: Institutional Journal Costs in an Open Access Environment
- Index(es):