[Date Prev][Date Next][Thread Prev][Thread Next][Date Index][Thread Index]
RE: Price discrimination for academic subscriptions (discussion)
- To: <liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu>
- Subject: RE: Price discrimination for academic subscriptions (discussion)
- From: "David Goodman" <David.Goodman@liu.edu>
- Date: Wed, 3 Sep 2003 23:05:52 EDT
- Reply-to: liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
- Sender: owner-liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
In the print era, it was very different when we paid *for what we might be likely to use*. The difficulty in obtaining items rapidly unless they were purchased in advance of possible use was much greater than it need be today. Thus, the extent to which a library purchased in advance meant the extent to which it could promply fill patrons' (unpredictable) needs. The libaries that could afford to do so extensively were the great libraries, the ones where good researchers wanted, because they alone could be efficient for far-reaching requirements. This of course need not be the case any longer. Thus the point of Phil's discusssion is that paying by the article is an equalizer--any library prepared to to buy online material by the article without staff mediation can deliver anything (that is so available) instantaneously. The economic problem for the publishers, is that even the best libraries can also take advantage of this technique, at least for the less-used materials. Thus the revenue that publishers have been in the habit of getting from the libraries that bought (almost) everything in advance will not be there. This revenue can be large, and I am not sure that the revenue from the many small libraries buying what they previously couldn't have afforded will equal it. There was a time as selector in such a library when I would unquestionably buy a $500 journal if it were used even once every few years, and a $5000 one used a few times a year. It's been a while, of course, since I deliberately did that--but the difference between the major and minor libraries remained the level of cost per use they were willing to accept. Now it can be the same for everyone. Will this provide enough revenue to keep the current system going with affordable prices per use? It would seem in principal that it could be revenue-neutral. In practice, I suspect that seeing the true costs and use more directly will and should lead to a somewhat changed system, in which some types of journals from some sources may no longer have a role. Dr. David Goodman Associate Professor Palmer School of Library and Information Science Long Island University dgoodman@liu.edu (and, formerly: Princeton University Library) -----Original Message----- From: Phil Davis [mailto:pmd8@cornell.edu] Sent: Wed 9/3/2003 6:44 PM To: liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu Subject: Price discrimination for academic subscriptions (discussion) Heather Morrison provided an excellent response and discussion to my original post regarding price discrimination. Without diverting into arguing over specific details, I would like to resubmit for discussion that any institutional classification (FTE, Carnegie Class, number of biologists, etc), are merely estimates of real (or potential) use. Are the consequences for paying for what you use any different than paying for what you *may be likely to use*. In other words, what would be the economic effects of moving to an economic pricing model whereby an institutions's price is at least partly based on that institution's usage pattern? --Phil Davis
- Prev by Date: Accessing ACRL Scholarly Communication principles
- Next by Date: Re: copyright protection paper
- Previous by thread: RE: Price discrimination for academic subscriptions (discussion)
- Next by thread: RE: Price discrimination for academic subscriptions (discussion)
- Index(es):