[Date Prev][Date Next][Thread Prev][Thread Next][Date Index][Thread Index]
RE: The embargo debate: tenor and motivations
- To: "'liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu'" <liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu>
- Subject: RE: The embargo debate: tenor and motivations
- From: "Price, Vince" <vince.price@il.proquest.com>
- Date: Fri, 27 Jul 2001 17:32:47 EDT
- Reply-To: liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
- Sender: owner-liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu
I think Mr. Carlson has accurately identified the key points of the debate. Whatever the counts happen to be, two questions are raised. One is a question of editorial policy in the design of databases as it relates to embargoes. The second question is about the strategic exclusives. Editorial Considerations --------------------------------------------- The respective needs of ARL's, community colleges, public libraries, K12, etc. are different. In building products for these audiences, database publishers establish editorial policies and make investments in: - Title counts (index only, embargo, non-embargo, peer reviewed, etc) - Interface ease-of-use - Currency of full text and indexing - Completeness (how many articles from a publication are included) - Index power (index fields, quality of vocabularies, number of terms applied). - Quality of service, support and training. The inclusion of embargoed titles in a database is an editorial decision relative to the target market for the product. However, is bigger always better? Should aggregators dump all the content they can get into one huge database? Are large, general reference databases a substitute for more specialized databases with robust, detailed, subject-specific indexing? We know from our usage logs that the majority of usage in periodical databases is in the most recent 12 months. Does a library value two titles equally when one has an embargo and the other does not? It costs the same to manufacture, index and deliver an embargoed title as a non-embargoed title. The editorial decision that the aggregator faces is to decide if the value of embargoed content as measured by library subscriptions covers its costs. I agree with Mr. Carlson's conclusion that librarians will decide which databases best meet their needs. Consortia are another factor to consider. Consortia (especially multi-type consortia) serve multiple constituents. Title counts and price are often the most convenient decision criteria. This drives vendors to build the largest counts possible at the lowest price with secondary consideration for other product attributes. However, think about the journal publisher's point-of-view. If title counts rise faster than database subscription revenue as aggregators bulk up title counts, any one publisher's earned royalty goes down in the long run. As a journal publisher manages its whole revenue from print subscriptions, reprints, microform, document delivery and databases, it is reasonable that such a dynamic would influence embargo policies. It also suggests why a publisher would be attracted to the guarantees associated with exclusive agreements. More content for more money works for publishers. More content for less does not. For a good article on that topic read "A license to Deal" by Tom Sanville from the February 15, 1999 issue of Library Journal. I would challenge the argument made by Mr. Carlson that no aggregator would ever want an embargo. But first let me state for the record before we are again falsely accused, that we do not advocate the cancellation of print in favor of access to content through aggregated databases. In fact, libraries need to understand that licensed aggregated databases are a service and not a collection in the traditional sense. Libraries must decide what material they need to hold for the long term in print, microform or electronic formats with perpetual licenses. I do believe that embargoes on certain content are here to stay and that libraries will need to fill the gap with either print subscriptions or e-journals. With that said, it is conceivable that an aggregator that is also a subscription agent may want to delay the migration to electronic access by advocating embargoes to protect its print service. This would accelerate the implementation of embargoes. Ultimately, all successful aggregators must support publisher efforts to maximize its whole revenue stream. The question is how long through the transition. Strategic Exclusives --------------------------------------- As discussed in a prior thread on this list, the pursuit of strategic exclusives started about one year ago. It is clear that the goal is to limit library choice to drive increased market share. ProQuest is responsible to our subscribers to defend our products in light of this strategy. We recently secured and announced preferred agreements with two major scholarly publishers that were formerly exclusive with another vendor. The result is that a large number of titles will return to ProQuest and will be halted in a competitor's databases in 2002. If we extend this case study, libraries can expect an increase in the number of exclusive titles as vendors try to carve out an advantage. Further, these exclusives will move from vendor to vendor every few years as vendors work to overcome a competitor's advantage. Thus titles will constantly be moving around making all databases more volatile. Finally we should expect costs to rise because exclusives are expensive. Mr. Carlson stated that he assumed that no vendor would secure an exclusive unless it was cost effective relative to the value of the publication. However, if the goal build a very high share of the whole market, it may be better to think of the guarantees as investments that will be covered over time by higher profits associated with a high share and only remotely connected to the specific content being exclusively licensed. Does the strategy support the underlying needs of libraries? Is it sustainable? Will libraries reward the vendor that builds the largest number of exclusive titles? Aggregators will watch the last question very closely. Finally, I cannot resist the temptation to offer one point in the marketing debate regarding claim about active, non-embargoed, peer-reviewed titles. ProQuest offers over 1,000 active, non-embargoed, peer-reviewed titles from nearly 700 unique publishers. We can find only 670 such titles from 340 publishers in our competitor's offering. Including planned titles that are not yet available for searching brings the number only to 800. ProQuest has a wide lead in this measure contrary to claims otherwise. Admittedly, the ProQuest titles are split among several databases as dictated by the editorial policy of the individual files while our competitor includes nearly all of these title in a single database regardless of content subject. Vince Price Vice President - ProQuest Marketing ProQuest Information and Learning Ph: 800-521-0600 Fax: 734-761-4700 -----Original Message----- From: Carlson, David [mailto:DCarlson@bridgew.edu] Sent: Thursday, July 26,2001 9:09 AM To: 'liblicense-l@lists.yale.edu' Subject: The embargo debate: tenor and motivations My two cents: It's unfortunate, I think, that the current debate on embargoes seems to be turning in to something of an Ebsco vs. ProQuest marketing debate. I'm not sure I have a winning suggestion to address this. I think some of the numbers and analysis recently presented are interesting and informative but I hope the discussion is more generic and less "he said, she said" (or rather: Ebsco said, ProQuest said....). I know vendor representatives have biases -- and that's fine. I'm also sure they're writing the truth as they know it, or at least are presenting their particular truths as they see them and want them to be presented. OK. The data IS informative but whatever the numbers, it is not that Ebsco is the bad guy and ProQuest the good; or vice versa. Stating the obvious: it is our job, as librarians, to evaluate the content of these databases, the cost, the interface, the relevance to our needs AND the level and use of embargoes (as well as other factors) to make the best possible selection decisions for our institutions that we can make. We get paid for this. Other than this, I would like to make one comment on the content of the discussion. I find it logical that an aggregator, such as Ebsco or ProQuest, would *not* prefer embargoes. This only makes business sense. If I, as a vendor, could offer you a full text database where all the titles have no embargo periods (and all the children are above average....) this is a clear marketing and strategic advantage. I don't think any aggregator would try to get titles with embargoes (unless there were cost factors which would make an embargo-less title too expensive for inclusion otherwise). I can readily understand, however, why *publishers* might require embargoes of titles in aggregator databases. The motivations are obvious. It would be nice to hear from publishers in this regard. I do not, however, see the same logic and motivation with exclusivity agreements. I can understand why aggregators would prefer and even recruit for exclusive agreements with publishers -- as long as they felt it was cost-effective relative to the value of the publication. I agree with others who have expressed their concern about this development. Its implications have concerns at several levels. David Carlson Director of Libraries Bridgewater State College Bridgewater, MA 02325 Work: 508-531-1256 Fax: 508-531-5255 <mailto:dcarlson@bridgew.edu> dcarlson@bridgew.edu <http://www.bridgew.edu/library> www.bridgew.edu/library
- Prev by Date: RE: Tempestuous Argument
- Next by Date: Re: The embargo debate: tenor and motivations
- Prev by thread: Re: The embargo debate: tenor and motivations
- Next by thread: Re: The embargo debate: tenor and motivations
- Index(es):